Citation: |
[1] |
R. Amir, Continuous stochastic games of capital accumulation with convex transitions, Games and Economic Behavior, 15 (1996), 111-131.doi: 10.1006/game.1996.0061. |
[2] |
R. Amir, F. Garcia and J. Resende, Dynamic monopoly pricing under discounted network effects, mimeo, 2016. |
[3] |
R. Amir and Natalia Lazzati, Network effects, market structure and industry performance, Journal of Economic Theory, 146 (2011), 2389-2419.doi: 10.1016/j.jet.2011.10.006. |
[4] |
W. Amaldoss and S. Jain, Conspicuous Consumption and sophisticated thinking, Management Science, 51 (2005), 1449-1466.doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1050.0399. |
[5] |
L. S. Bagwell and B. D. Bernheim, Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption, The American Economic Review, 86 (1996), 349-373. |
[6] |
G. S. Becker, A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influences on price, Journal of Political Economy, 99 (1991), 1109-1116.doi: 10.1086/261791. |
[7] |
B. D. Bernheim, A theory of conformity, The Journal of Political Economy, 102 (1994), 841-877.doi: 10.1086/261957. |
[8] |
S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer and I. Welch, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades, Journal of Political Economy, 100 (1994), 992-1026. |
[9] |
L. Cabral, Dynamic price competition with network effects, Review of Economic Studies, 78 (2011), 83-111.doi: 10.1093/restud/rdq007. |
[10] |
G. Corneo and O. Jeanne, Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism, Journal of Public Economics, 66 (1997), 55-71.doi: 10.1016/S0047-2727(97)00016-9. |
[11] |
G. Corneo and O. Jeanne, Segmented communication and fashionable behavior, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 39 (1999), 371-385.doi: 10.1016/S0167-2681(99)00046-3. |
[12] |
R. Cowan, W. Cowan and G. Swann, A model of demand with interactions among consumers, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15 (1997), 711-732.doi: 10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00008-8. |
[13] |
C. d'Aspremont, J. J. Gabszewicz and J. Thisse, On hotelling's stability in competition, Econometrica, 47 (1979), 1145-1150.doi: 10.2307/1911955. |
[14] |
T. Doganoglu, Dynamic competition with consumption externalities, Netnomics, 5 (2003), 116-135. |
[15] |
U. Doraszelski, J. Chen and J. Harrington, Avoiding market dominance: Product compatibility in markets with network effects, RAND Journal of Economics, 40 (2009), 455-485. |
[16] |
J. J. Gabszewicz and F. Garcia, Optimal monopoly price paths with expanding networks, Review of Network Economics, 6 (2007), 142-149. |
[17] |
J. J. Gabszewicz and F. Garcia, A note on expanding networks and monopoly pricing, Economics Letters, 98 (2008), 9-15.doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2007.03.012. |
[18] |
I. Grilo, O. Shy and J. Thisse, Price competition when consumer behavior is characterized by conformity or vanity, Journal of Public Economics, 80 (2001), 385-408.doi: 10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00115-8. |
[19] |
S. R. G. Jones, The Economics of Conformism, Basil Blackwell, New York, 1984. |
[20] |
E. Karni and D. Schmeidler, Fixed preferences and changing tastes, The American Economic Review, 80 (1990), 262-267. |
[21] |
M. Katz and C. Shapiro, Network effect, competition, and compatibility, American Economic Review, 75 (1985), 424-440. |
[22] |
D. Kuksov and K. Wang, A model of the "it" products in fashion, Marketing Science, 32 (2013), 51-69. |
[23] |
D. Kuksov and Y. Xie, Competition in a status goods market, Journal of Marketing Research, 49 (2012), 609-623.doi: 10.1509/jmr.11.0005. |
[24] |
D. Laussel, M. Montmarin and N. Van Long, Dynamic duopoly with congestion effects, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22 (2004), 655-677.doi: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2004.02.001. |
[25] |
D. Laussel and J. Resende, Dynamic price competition in aftermarkets with network effects, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 50 (2014), 106-118.doi: 10.1016/j.jmateco.2013.10.002. |
[26] |
S. Markovich, Snowball: A dynamic oligopoly model with indirect network effects, Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 32 (2008), 909-938.doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2007.04.005. |
[27] |
S. Markovich and J. Moenius, Winning while losing: competition dynamics in the presence of indirect network effects, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27 (2009), 346-357.doi: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2008.10.006. |
[28] |
P. Milgrom and J. Roberts, Rationalizability, learning, and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities, Econometrica, 58 (1990), 1255-1277.doi: 10.2307/2938316. |
[29] |
M. Mitchell and A. Skrzypacz, Network externalities and long-run market shares, Economic Theory, 29 (2006), 621-648.doi: 10.1007/s00199-005-0031-0. |
[30] |
W. Pesendorfer, Design innovation and fashion cycles, The American Economic Review, 85 (1995), 771-792. |
[31] |
D. Robinson, The economics of fashion demand, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75 (1961), 376-398.doi: 10.2307/1885130. |
[32] |
L. Ross, G. Bierbrauer and S. Hoffman, The role of attribution processes in conformity and dissent: Revisiting the Asch situation, American Psychologist, 3 (1976), 148-157.doi: 10.1037/0003-066X.31.2.148. |
[33] |
R. Rumbold, The it-bag parade, Daily Telegraph, (November 25), 2007, http://fashion.telegraph.co.uk/news-features/TMG3363792/ The-it-bag-parade.html. |
[34] |
D. M. Topkis, Equilibrium points in nonzero-sum n-person submodular games, SIAM Journal of Control and Optimization, 17 (1979), 773-787.doi: 10.1137/0317054. |
[35] |
X. Vives, Nash equilibrium with strategic complementarities, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 19 (1990), 305-321.doi: 10.1016/0304-4068(90)90005-T. |
[36] |
X. Vives, Complementarities and games: New developments, Journal of Economic Literature, 43 (2005), 437-479.doi: 10.1257/0022051054661558. |
[37] |
T. Veblen, The Theory of the Leisure Class. An Economic Study of Institutions, George Allen Unwin, London (1922) (First published, 1899). |
[38] |
H. Yoganarasimhan, Cloak or flaunt? The fashion dilemma, Marketing Science, 31 (2012), 74-95.doi: 10.1287/mksc.1110.0689. |