In this paper, we introduce a large system of interacting financial agents in which all agents are faced with the decision of how to allocate their capital between a risky stock or a risk-less bond. The investment decision of investors, derived through an optimization, drives the stock price. The model has been inspired by the econophysical Levy-Levy-Solomon model [
Citation: |
Figure 4. Quantile-quantile plot of logarithmic stock return distribution (left-hand side) and logarithmic return of fundamental prices (right-hand side). The simulation has been performed in the case of long-term investors and a stochastic fundamental price. The risk tolerance has been set to $ \gamma = 0.9 $, the scale to $ \rho = \frac{5}{8} $ and the random seed is chosen to be $\texttt{rng(767)}$. All further parameters are chosen as reported in section A.4 of the Appendix
[1] | G. Albi, M. Herty and L. Pareschi, Kinetic description of optimal control problems and applications to opinion consensus, Communications in Mathematical Sciences, 13 (2015), 1407-1429. doi: 10.4310/CMS.2015.v13.n6.a3. |
[2] | G. Albi, L. Pareschi and M. Zanella, Boltzmann-type control of opinion consensus through leaders, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences, 372 (2014), 20140138, 18pp. doi: 10.1098/rsta.2014.0138. |
[3] | A. Beja and M. B. Goldman, On the dynamic behavior of prices in disequilibrium, The Journal of Finance, 35 (1980), 235-248. |
[4] | D. Bertsimas and D. Pachamanova, Robust multiperiod portfolio management in the presence of transaction costs, Computers & Operations Research, 35 (2008), 3-17. doi: 10.1016/j.cor.2006.02.011. |
[5] | M. Bisi, G. Spiga and G. Toscani, et al., Kinetic models of conservative economies with wealth redistribution, Communications in Mathematical Sciences, 7 (2009), 901-916. doi: 10.4310/CMS.2009.v7.n4.a5. |
[6] | J.-P. Bouchaud and M. Mézard, Wealth condensation in a simple model of economy, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 282 (2000), 536-545. doi: 10.1016/S0378-4371(00)00205-3. |
[7] | W. Braun and K. Hepp, The Vlasov dynamics and its fluctuations in the 1/N limit of interacting classical particles, Communications in Mathematical Physics, 56 (1977), 101-113. doi: 10.1007/BF01611497. |
[8] | W. A. Brock and C. H. Hommes, Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 22 (1998), 1235-1274. doi: 10.1016/S0165-1889(98)00011-6. |
[9] | M. Burger, L. Caffarelli, P. A. Markowich and M.-T. Wolfram, On a Boltzmann-type price formation model, Proc. R. Soc. A, 469 (2013), 20130126, 20pp. doi: 10.1098/rspa.2013.0126. |
[10] | E. Camacho and C. Bordons, Model Predictive Control, Springer, USA, 2004. |
[11] | A. Chatterjee and B. K. Chakrabarti, Kinetic exchange models for income and wealth distributions, The European Physical Journal B-Condensed Matter and Complex Systems, 60 (2007), 135-149. doi: 10.1140/epjb/e2007-00343-8. |
[12] | L. Chayes, M. del Mar González, M. P. Gualdani and I. Kim, Global existence and uniqueness of solutions to a model of price formation, SIAM Journal on Mathematical Analysis, 41 (2009), 2107-2135. doi: 10.1137/090753346. |
[13] | J. Che, A kinetic model on portfolio in finance, Communications in Mathematical Sciences, 9 (2011), 1073-1096. doi: 10.4310/CMS.2011.v9.n4.a7. |
[14] | C. Chiarella, R. Dieci and X.-Z. He, Heterogeneous expectations and speculative behavior in a dynamic multi-asset framework, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 62 (2007), 408-427. |
[15] | D. Colander, H. Föllmer, A. Haas, M. D. Goldberg, K. Juselius, A. Kirman, T. Lux and B. Sloth, The financial crisis and the systemic failure of academic economics, 2009. |
[16] | R. Cont, Empirical properties of asset returns: Stylized facts and statistical issues, 2001. |
[17] | S. Cordier, L. Pareschi and C. Piatecki, Mesoscopic modelling of financial markets, Journal of Statistical Physics, 134 (2009), 161-184. doi: 10.1007/s10955-008-9667-z. |
[18] | S. Cordier, L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, On a kinetic model for a simple market economy, Journal of Statistical Physics, 120 (2005), 253-277. doi: 10.1007/s10955-005-5456-0. |
[19] | R. Cross, M. Grinfeld, H. Lamba and T. Seaman, A threshold model of investor psychology, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 354 (2005), 463-478. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2005.02.029. |
[20] | M. Delitala and T. Lorenzi, A mathematical model for value estimation with public information and herding, Kinetic & Related Models, 7 (2014), 29-44. doi: 10.3934/krm.2014.7.29. |
[21] | R. L. Dobrushin, Vlasov equations, Functional Analysis and Its Applications, 13 (1979), 115-123. |
[22] | B. Düring, D. Matthes and G. Toscani, Kinetic equations modelling wealth redistribution: A comparison of approaches, Physical Review E, 78 (2008), 056103, 12pp. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.78.056103. |
[23] | E. Egenter, T. Lux and D. Stauffer, Finite-size effects in Monte Carlo simulations of two stock market models, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 268 (1999), 250-256. doi: 10.1016/S0378-4371(99)00059-X. |
[24] | J. D. Farmer and D. Foley, The economy needs agent-based modelling, Nature, 460 (2009), 685-686. doi: 10.1038/460685a. |
[25] | T. Hellthaler, The influence of investor number on a microscopic market model, International Journal of Modern Physics C, 6 (1996), 845-852. doi: 10.1142/S0129183195000691. |
[26] | D. Kahneman and A. Tversky, Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 47 (1979), 263-291. doi: 10.2307/1914185. |
[27] | K. Kanazawa, T. Sueshige, H. Takayasu and M. Takayasu, Derivation of the boltzmann equation for financial brownian motion: direct observation of the collective motion of high-frequency traders, Physical Review Letters, 120 (2018), 138301. doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.120.138301. |
[28] | K. Kanazawa, T. Sueshige, H. Takayasu and M. Takayasu, Kinetic theory for finance brownian motion from microscopic dynamics, arXiv: 1802.05993, 2018. |
[29] | R. Kohl, The influence of the number of different stocks on the Levy–Levy–Solomon model, International Journal of Modern Physics C, 8 (1997), 1309-1316. doi: 10.1142/S0129183197001168. |
[30] | M. Levy, H. Levy and S. Solomon, A microscopic model of the stock market: Cycles, booms, and crashes, Economics Letters, 45 (1994), 103-111. |
[31] | T. Lux et al., Stochastic Behavioral Asset Pricing Models and the Stylized Facts, Technical report, Economics working paper/Christian-Albrechts-Universität Kiel, Department of Economics, 2008. |
[32] | T. Lux and M. Marchesi, Scaling and criticality in a stochastic multi-agent model of a financial market, Nature, 397 (1999), 498-500. doi: 10.1038/17290. |
[33] | D. Maldarella and L. Pareschi, Kinetic models for socio-economic dynamics of speculative markets, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 391 (2012), 715-730. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2011.08.013. |
[34] | H. Markowitz, Portfolio selection, The Journal of Finance, 7 (1952), 77-91. |
[35] | D. Matthes and G. Toscani, Analysis of a model for wealth redistribution, Kinetic and Related Models, 1 (2008), 1-22. doi: 10.3934/krm.2008.1.1. |
[36] | D. Q. Mayne and H. Michalska, Receding horizon control of nonlinear systems, IEEE Trans. Automat. Control, 35 (1990), 814-824. doi: 10.1109/9.57020. |
[37] | R. C. Merton, Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case, The review of Economics and Statistics, 51 (1969), 247-257. doi: 10.2307/1926560. |
[38] | J. E. Mitchell and S. Braun, Rebalancing an investment portfolio in the presence of convex transaction costs, including market impact costs, Optimization Methods and Software, 28 (2013), 523-542. doi: 10.1080/10556788.2012.717940. |
[39] | H. Neunzert, The Vlasov equation as a limit of Hamiltonian classical mechanical systems of interacting particles, Trans. Fluid Dynamics, 18 (1977), 663-678. |
[40] | A. Pagan, The econometrics of financial markets, Journal of Empirical Finance, 3 (1996), 15-102. doi: 10.1016/0927-5398(95)00020-8. |
[41] | L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, Journal of statistical physics, 124 (2006), 747-779. doi: 10.1007/s10955-006-9025-y. |
[42] | L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Interacting Multiagent Systems: Kinetic Equations and Monte Carlo Methods, Oxford University Press, 2013. |
[43] | H. A. Simon, A behavioral model of rational choice, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69 (1955), 99-118. doi: 10.2307/1884852. |
[44] | D. Sornette, Physics and financial economics (1776–2014): Puzzles, Ising and agent-based models, Reports on Progress in Physics, 77 (2014), 062001, 28pp. doi: 10.1088/0034-4885/77/6/062001. |
[45] | A.-S. Sznitman, Topics in propagation of chaos, In Ecole d'Eté de Probabilités de Saint-Flour XIX-1989, 165–251, Lecture Notes in Math., 1464, Springer, Berlin, 1991. doi: 10.1007/BFb0085169. |
[46] | T. Trimborn, M. Frank and S. Martin, Mean field limit of a behavioral financial market model, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 505 (2018), 613-631. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2018.03.079. |
[47] | C. Villani, On a new class of weak solutions to the spatially homogeneous Boltzmann and Landau equations, Archive for Rational Mechanics and Analysis, 143 (1998), 273-307. doi: 10.1007/s002050050106. |
[48] | L. Walras., Études D'économie Politique Appliquée: (Théorie de la Production de la Richesse Sociale), F. Rouge, 1898. |
[49] | E. Zschischang and T. Lux, Some new results on the Levy, Levy and Solomon microscopic stock market model, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 291 (2001), 563-573. doi: 10.1016/S0378-4371(00)00609-9. |
Sketch of the modelling process
Example of the value function
Stock price evolution in the long-term investor case with a constant fundamental price
Quantile-quantile plot of logarithmic stock return distribution (left-hand side) and logarithmic return of fundamental prices (right-hand side). The simulation has been performed in the case of long-term investors and a stochastic fundamental price. The risk tolerance has been set to
Stock price distribution in the long-term investor case. The solid lines are analytical solution, whereas the circles are the numerical result
Distribution of the wealth invested in stocks with a Gaussian fit (solid line). Left figure has a linear scale, whereas the right figure shows the distribution in log-log scale
Distribution of the wealth invested in bonds in the special case
Stock price distribution in the high-frequency case (red circles). The fit by the inverse-gamma distribution (solid line) clearly underestimates the tail. This reveals that the full model can create heavier tails than the inverse-gamma distribution
Marginal wealth distributions in the high-frequency investor case. The left hand side illustrates the distribution of investments in stocks and the right-hand side the wealth invested in bonds at
Steady state stock price distribution in the high-frequency investor case (circles) together with the analytically computed steady state of inverse-gamma type (solid line)