April  2016, 3(2): 191-216. doi: 10.3934/jdg.2016010

Conflict and segregation in networks: An experiment on the interplay between individual preferences and social influence

1. 

Institute of Sociology and Social Psychology, University of Cologne, Cologne, Germany

2. 

ERI-CES, Departamento de Análisis Económico, Universitat de Valencia, Avenida Los Naranjos s/n, Campus de Tarongers, Valencia, 46022, Spain, Spain, Spain

Received  February 2016 Revised  April 2016 Published  April 2016

We examine the interplay between a person's individual preference and the social influence others exert. We provide a model of network relationships with conflicting preferences, where individuals are better off coordinating with those around them, but where not all have a preference for the same action. We test our model in an experiment, varying the level of conflicting preferences between individuals. Our findings suggest that preferences are more salient than social influence, under conflicting preferences: subjects relate mainly with others who have the same preferences. This leads to two undesirable outcomes: network segregation and social inefficiency. The same force that helps people individually, hurts society.
Citation: Lea Ellwardt, Penélope Hernández, Guillem Martínez-Cánovas, Manuel Muñoz-Herrera. Conflict and segregation in networks: An experiment on the interplay between individual preferences and social influence. Journal of Dynamics & Games, 2016, 3 (2) : 191-216. doi: 10.3934/jdg.2016010
References:
[1]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Economics and identity,, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (2000), 715.  doi: 10.1515/9781400834181.  Google Scholar

[2]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity and schooling: Some lessons for the economics of education,, Journal of economic literature, 40 (2002), 1167.  doi: 10.1257/.40.4.1167.  Google Scholar

[3]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity and the economics of organizations,, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (2005), 9.  doi: 10.1257/0895330053147930.  Google Scholar

[4]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity Economics: How Our Identities Shape Our Work, Wages, and Well-Being,, Princeton University Press, (2010).   Google Scholar

[5]

V. Bala and S. Goyal, A noncooperative model of network formation,, Econometrica, 68 (2000), 1181.  doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00155.  Google Scholar

[6]

C. Ballester, A. Calvó-Armengol and Y. Zenou, Who's who in networks. wanted: The key player,, Econometrica, 74 (2006), 1403.  doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00709.x.  Google Scholar

[7]

H. Bernhard, E. Fehr and U. Fischbacher, Group affiliation and altruistic norm enforcement,, The American Economic Review, 96 (2006), 217.  doi: 10.1257/000282806777212594.  Google Scholar

[8]

M. Billig and H. Tajfel, Social categorization and similarity in intergroup behaviour,, European Journal of Social Psychology, 3 (1973), 27.  doi: 10.1002/ejsp.2420030103.  Google Scholar

[9]

M. B. Brewer, In-group bias in the minimal intergroup situation: A cognitive-motivational analysis,, Psychological bulletin, 86 (1979), 307.  doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.86.2.307.  Google Scholar

[10]

A. Calvó-Armengol and R. İlkılıç, Pairwise-stability and nash equilibria in network formation,, International Journal of Game Theory, 38 (2009), 51.  doi: 10.1007/s00182-008-0140-7.  Google Scholar

[11]

C. Camerer, Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction,, Princeton University Press, (2003).   Google Scholar

[12]

G. Charness, L. Rigotti and A. Rustichini, Individual behavior and group membership,, The American Economic Review, (): 1340.  doi: 10.2139/ssrn.894685.  Google Scholar

[13]

Y. Chen and S. X. Li, Group identity and social preferences,, The American Economic Review, 99 (2009), 431.  doi: 10.1257/aer.99.1.431.  Google Scholar

[14]

G. Ellison, Learning, local interaction, and coordination,, Econometrica, 61 (1993), 1047.  doi: 10.2307/2951493.  Google Scholar

[15]

J. Farrell and M. Rabin, Cheap talk,, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (1996), 103.  doi: 10.1257/jep.10.3.103.  Google Scholar

[16]

U. Fischbacher, z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments,, Experimental economics, 10 (2007), 171.  doi: 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4.  Google Scholar

[17]

A. Galeotti, S. Goyal, M. Jackson, F. Vega-Redondo and L. Yariv, Network games,, Review of Economic Studies, 77 (2010), 218.  doi: 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00570.x.  Google Scholar

[18]

L. Goette, D. Huffman and S. Meier, The impact of group membership on cooperation and norm enforcement: Evidence using random assignment to real social groups,, The American economic review, 96 (2006), 212.  doi: 10.1257/000282806777211658.  Google Scholar

[19]

S. Goyal, Connections: An Introduction to the Economics of Networks,, Princeton University Press, (2007).   Google Scholar

[20]

M. Granovetter, Threshold models of collective behavior,, American journal of sociology, 83 (1978), 1420.  doi: 10.1086/226707.  Google Scholar

[21]

P. Hernández, M. Muñoz-Herrera and Á. Sánchez, Heterogeneous network games,, Games and Economic Behavior, 79 (2013).  doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2013.01.004.  Google Scholar

[22]

M. O. Jackson, A survey of network formation models: Stability and efficiency,, Group Formation in Economics: Networks, (2010), 11.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511614385.002.  Google Scholar

[23]

M. O. Jackson, Networks and economic behavior,, Annu. Rev. Econ., 1 (2009), 489.  doi: 10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.143238.  Google Scholar

[24]

M. O. Jackson, Social and Economic Networks,, Princeton University Press, (2008).   Google Scholar

[25]

M. O. Jackson and A. Watts, The existence of pairwise stable networks,, Seoul Journal of Economics., ().   Google Scholar

[26]

M. O. Jackson and A. Watts, On the formation of interaction networks in social coordination games,, Games and Economic Behavior, 41 (2002), 265.  doi: 10.1016/S0899-8256(02)00504-3.  Google Scholar

[27]

M. O. Jackson and A. Wolinsky, A strategic model of social and economic networks,, Journal of economic theory, 71 (1996), 44.  doi: 10.1006/jeth.1996.0108.  Google Scholar

[28]

M. Kandori, G. J. Mailath and R. Rob, Learning, mutation, and long run equilibria in games,, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 61 (1993), 29.  doi: 10.2307/2951777.  Google Scholar

[29]

G. J. Leonardelli and M. B. Brewer, Minority and majority discrimination: When and why,, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 37 (2001), 468.  doi: 10.1006/jesp.2001.1475.  Google Scholar

[30]

D. López-Pintado, Contagion and coordination in random networks,, International Journal of Game Theory, 34 (2006), 371.  doi: 10.1007/s00182-006-0026-5.  Google Scholar

[31]

P. V. Marsden, Network diversity, substructures, and opportunities for contact,, Structures of power and constraint: Papers in honor of Peter Blau, (): 397.   Google Scholar

[32]

M. McPherson, L. Smith-Lovin and J. M. Cook, Birds of a feather: Homophily in social networks,, Annual review of sociology, 27 (2001), 415.  doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415.  Google Scholar

[33]

S. Morris, Contagion,, The Review of Economic Studies, 67 (2000), 57.  doi: 10.1111/1467-937X.00121.  Google Scholar

[34]

B. Mullen, R. Brown and C. Smith, Ingroup bias as a function of salience, relevance, and status: An integration,, European Journal of Social Psychology, 22 (1992), 103.  doi: 10.1002/ejsp.2420220202.  Google Scholar

[35]

M. Muñoz-Herrera, J. Dijkstra, A. Flache and R. Wittek, How specialization can breed social exclusion: A model of strategic interaction between pecialists and generalists in knowledge-intensive productive exchange,, Working Paper, ().   Google Scholar

[36]

T. Schelling, Micromotives and Macrobehavior,, New York: WW Norton, (1978).   Google Scholar

[37]

T. Snijders and R. J. Bosker, Multilevel Analysis: An Introduction to Basic and Applied Multilevel Analysis,, 2nd edition, (2012).   Google Scholar

[38]

H. Tajfel and J. C. Turner, An integrative theory of intergroup conflict,, The social psychology of intergroup relations, 33 (1979).   Google Scholar

[39]

J. C. Turner, Social categorization and social discrimination in the minimal group paradigm,, Differentiation between social groups: Studies in the social psychology of intergroup relations, (): 101.   Google Scholar

[40]

J. C. Turner, M. A. Hogg, P. J. Oakes, S. D. Reicher and M. S. Wetherell, Rediscovering the Social Group: A Self-Categorization Theory.,, Basil Blackwell, (1987).   Google Scholar

[41]

F. Vega-Redondo, Complex Social Networks, vol. 44,, Cambridge Univ Pr, (2007).  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511804052.  Google Scholar

[42]

L. M. Verbrugge, The structure of adult friendship choices,, Social Forces, 56 (1977), 576.   Google Scholar

[43]

X. Vives, Games with strategic complementarities: New applications to industrial organization,, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23 (2005), 625.  doi: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.04.002.  Google Scholar

[44]

H. P. Young, The evolution of conventions,, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 61 (1993), 57.  doi: 10.2307/2951778.  Google Scholar

show all references

References:
[1]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Economics and identity,, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (2000), 715.  doi: 10.1515/9781400834181.  Google Scholar

[2]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity and schooling: Some lessons for the economics of education,, Journal of economic literature, 40 (2002), 1167.  doi: 10.1257/.40.4.1167.  Google Scholar

[3]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity and the economics of organizations,, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (2005), 9.  doi: 10.1257/0895330053147930.  Google Scholar

[4]

G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, Identity Economics: How Our Identities Shape Our Work, Wages, and Well-Being,, Princeton University Press, (2010).   Google Scholar

[5]

V. Bala and S. Goyal, A noncooperative model of network formation,, Econometrica, 68 (2000), 1181.  doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00155.  Google Scholar

[6]

C. Ballester, A. Calvó-Armengol and Y. Zenou, Who's who in networks. wanted: The key player,, Econometrica, 74 (2006), 1403.  doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00709.x.  Google Scholar

[7]

H. Bernhard, E. Fehr and U. Fischbacher, Group affiliation and altruistic norm enforcement,, The American Economic Review, 96 (2006), 217.  doi: 10.1257/000282806777212594.  Google Scholar

[8]

M. Billig and H. Tajfel, Social categorization and similarity in intergroup behaviour,, European Journal of Social Psychology, 3 (1973), 27.  doi: 10.1002/ejsp.2420030103.  Google Scholar

[9]

M. B. Brewer, In-group bias in the minimal intergroup situation: A cognitive-motivational analysis,, Psychological bulletin, 86 (1979), 307.  doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.86.2.307.  Google Scholar

[10]

A. Calvó-Armengol and R. İlkılıç, Pairwise-stability and nash equilibria in network formation,, International Journal of Game Theory, 38 (2009), 51.  doi: 10.1007/s00182-008-0140-7.  Google Scholar

[11]

C. Camerer, Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction,, Princeton University Press, (2003).   Google Scholar

[12]

G. Charness, L. Rigotti and A. Rustichini, Individual behavior and group membership,, The American Economic Review, (): 1340.  doi: 10.2139/ssrn.894685.  Google Scholar

[13]

Y. Chen and S. X. Li, Group identity and social preferences,, The American Economic Review, 99 (2009), 431.  doi: 10.1257/aer.99.1.431.  Google Scholar

[14]

G. Ellison, Learning, local interaction, and coordination,, Econometrica, 61 (1993), 1047.  doi: 10.2307/2951493.  Google Scholar

[15]

J. Farrell and M. Rabin, Cheap talk,, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 (1996), 103.  doi: 10.1257/jep.10.3.103.  Google Scholar

[16]

U. Fischbacher, z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments,, Experimental economics, 10 (2007), 171.  doi: 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4.  Google Scholar

[17]

A. Galeotti, S. Goyal, M. Jackson, F. Vega-Redondo and L. Yariv, Network games,, Review of Economic Studies, 77 (2010), 218.  doi: 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00570.x.  Google Scholar

[18]

L. Goette, D. Huffman and S. Meier, The impact of group membership on cooperation and norm enforcement: Evidence using random assignment to real social groups,, The American economic review, 96 (2006), 212.  doi: 10.1257/000282806777211658.  Google Scholar

[19]

S. Goyal, Connections: An Introduction to the Economics of Networks,, Princeton University Press, (2007).   Google Scholar

[20]

M. Granovetter, Threshold models of collective behavior,, American journal of sociology, 83 (1978), 1420.  doi: 10.1086/226707.  Google Scholar

[21]

P. Hernández, M. Muñoz-Herrera and Á. Sánchez, Heterogeneous network games,, Games and Economic Behavior, 79 (2013).  doi: 10.1016/j.geb.2013.01.004.  Google Scholar

[22]

M. O. Jackson, A survey of network formation models: Stability and efficiency,, Group Formation in Economics: Networks, (2010), 11.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511614385.002.  Google Scholar

[23]

M. O. Jackson, Networks and economic behavior,, Annu. Rev. Econ., 1 (2009), 489.  doi: 10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.143238.  Google Scholar

[24]

M. O. Jackson, Social and Economic Networks,, Princeton University Press, (2008).   Google Scholar

[25]

M. O. Jackson and A. Watts, The existence of pairwise stable networks,, Seoul Journal of Economics., ().   Google Scholar

[26]

M. O. Jackson and A. Watts, On the formation of interaction networks in social coordination games,, Games and Economic Behavior, 41 (2002), 265.  doi: 10.1016/S0899-8256(02)00504-3.  Google Scholar

[27]

M. O. Jackson and A. Wolinsky, A strategic model of social and economic networks,, Journal of economic theory, 71 (1996), 44.  doi: 10.1006/jeth.1996.0108.  Google Scholar

[28]

M. Kandori, G. J. Mailath and R. Rob, Learning, mutation, and long run equilibria in games,, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 61 (1993), 29.  doi: 10.2307/2951777.  Google Scholar

[29]

G. J. Leonardelli and M. B. Brewer, Minority and majority discrimination: When and why,, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 37 (2001), 468.  doi: 10.1006/jesp.2001.1475.  Google Scholar

[30]

D. López-Pintado, Contagion and coordination in random networks,, International Journal of Game Theory, 34 (2006), 371.  doi: 10.1007/s00182-006-0026-5.  Google Scholar

[31]

P. V. Marsden, Network diversity, substructures, and opportunities for contact,, Structures of power and constraint: Papers in honor of Peter Blau, (): 397.   Google Scholar

[32]

M. McPherson, L. Smith-Lovin and J. M. Cook, Birds of a feather: Homophily in social networks,, Annual review of sociology, 27 (2001), 415.  doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415.  Google Scholar

[33]

S. Morris, Contagion,, The Review of Economic Studies, 67 (2000), 57.  doi: 10.1111/1467-937X.00121.  Google Scholar

[34]

B. Mullen, R. Brown and C. Smith, Ingroup bias as a function of salience, relevance, and status: An integration,, European Journal of Social Psychology, 22 (1992), 103.  doi: 10.1002/ejsp.2420220202.  Google Scholar

[35]

M. Muñoz-Herrera, J. Dijkstra, A. Flache and R. Wittek, How specialization can breed social exclusion: A model of strategic interaction between pecialists and generalists in knowledge-intensive productive exchange,, Working Paper, ().   Google Scholar

[36]

T. Schelling, Micromotives and Macrobehavior,, New York: WW Norton, (1978).   Google Scholar

[37]

T. Snijders and R. J. Bosker, Multilevel Analysis: An Introduction to Basic and Applied Multilevel Analysis,, 2nd edition, (2012).   Google Scholar

[38]

H. Tajfel and J. C. Turner, An integrative theory of intergroup conflict,, The social psychology of intergroup relations, 33 (1979).   Google Scholar

[39]

J. C. Turner, Social categorization and social discrimination in the minimal group paradigm,, Differentiation between social groups: Studies in the social psychology of intergroup relations, (): 101.   Google Scholar

[40]

J. C. Turner, M. A. Hogg, P. J. Oakes, S. D. Reicher and M. S. Wetherell, Rediscovering the Social Group: A Self-Categorization Theory.,, Basil Blackwell, (1987).   Google Scholar

[41]

F. Vega-Redondo, Complex Social Networks, vol. 44,, Cambridge Univ Pr, (2007).  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511804052.  Google Scholar

[42]

L. M. Verbrugge, The structure of adult friendship choices,, Social Forces, 56 (1977), 576.   Google Scholar

[43]

X. Vives, Games with strategic complementarities: New applications to industrial organization,, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23 (2005), 625.  doi: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.04.002.  Google Scholar

[44]

H. P. Young, The evolution of conventions,, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 61 (1993), 57.  doi: 10.2307/2951778.  Google Scholar

[1]

Evelyn Sander, Thomas Wanner. Equilibrium validation in models for pattern formation based on Sobolev embeddings. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2021, 26 (1) : 603-632. doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2020260

[2]

Jiannan Zhang, Ping Chen, Zhuo Jin, Shuanming Li. Open-loop equilibrium strategy for mean-variance portfolio selection: A log-return model. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (2) : 765-777. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019133

[3]

Manuel Friedrich, Martin Kružík, Ulisse Stefanelli. Equilibrium of immersed hyperelastic solids. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2021  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2021003

[4]

Xiaoxian Tang, Jie Wang. Bistability of sequestration networks. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2021, 26 (3) : 1337-1357. doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2020165

[5]

Simone Fagioli, Emanuela Radici. Opinion formation systems via deterministic particles approximation. Kinetic & Related Models, 2021, 14 (1) : 45-76. doi: 10.3934/krm.2020048

[6]

Niklas Kolbe, Nikolaos Sfakianakis, Christian Stinner, Christina Surulescu, Jonas Lenz. Modeling multiple taxis: Tumor invasion with phenotypic heterogeneity, haptotaxis, and unilateral interspecies repellence. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2021, 26 (1) : 443-481. doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2020284

[7]

Guo Zhou, Yongquan Zhou, Ruxin Zhao. Hybrid social spider optimization algorithm with differential mutation operator for the job-shop scheduling problem. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (2) : 533-548. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019122

[8]

D. R. Michiel Renger, Johannes Zimmer. Orthogonality of fluxes in general nonlinear reaction networks. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2021, 14 (1) : 205-217. doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020346

[9]

Bernold Fiedler. Global Hopf bifurcation in networks with fast feedback cycles. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2021, 14 (1) : 177-203. doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020344

[10]

Lars Grüne. Computing Lyapunov functions using deep neural networks. Journal of Computational Dynamics, 2020  doi: 10.3934/jcd.2021006

[11]

Pedro Aceves-Sanchez, Benjamin Aymard, Diane Peurichard, Pol Kennel, Anne Lorsignol, Franck Plouraboué, Louis Casteilla, Pierre Degond. A new model for the emergence of blood capillary networks. Networks & Heterogeneous Media, 2020  doi: 10.3934/nhm.2021001

[12]

Leslaw Skrzypek, Yuncheng You. Feedback synchronization of FHN cellular neural networks. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2021001

[13]

Alexandra Köthe, Anna Marciniak-Czochra, Izumi Takagi. Hysteresis-driven pattern formation in reaction-diffusion-ODE systems. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - A, 2020, 40 (6) : 3595-3627. doi: 10.3934/dcds.2020170

[14]

Xin Zhong. Singularity formation to the nonhomogeneous magneto-micropolar fluid equations. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2021  doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2021021

[15]

Yong-Jung Kim, Hyowon Seo, Changwook Yoon. Asymmetric dispersal and evolutional selection in two-patch system. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - A, 2020, 40 (6) : 3571-3593. doi: 10.3934/dcds.2020043

[16]

Hongfei Yang, Xiaofeng Ding, Raymond Chan, Hui Hu, Yaxin Peng, Tieyong Zeng. A new initialization method based on normed statistical spaces in deep networks. Inverse Problems & Imaging, 2021, 15 (1) : 147-158. doi: 10.3934/ipi.2020045

[17]

Bing Liu, Ming Zhou. Robust portfolio selection for individuals: Minimizing the probability of lifetime ruin. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (2) : 937-952. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2020005

[18]

Junkee Jeon. Finite horizon portfolio selection problems with stochastic borrowing constraints. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (2) : 733-763. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019132

[19]

Lin Jiang, Song Wang. Robust multi-period and multi-objective portfolio selection. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (2) : 695-709. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019130

[20]

H. M. Srivastava, H. I. Abdel-Gawad, Khaled Mohammed Saad. Oscillatory states and patterns formation in a two-cell cubic autocatalytic reaction-diffusion model subjected to the Dirichlet conditions. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020433

 Impact Factor: 

Metrics

  • PDF downloads (71)
  • HTML views (0)
  • Cited by (7)

[Back to Top]