Preference | $\succeq_{c_{2}}$3 | |||
$\frac{k_{A}}{k_{B}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$B$ $A$ |
$A/B$ $B/A$ |
$A$ $B$ |
Agenda setting is a key feature of political systems. We propose a novel approach to contrast the respective power of candidates and parties when bargaining over agenda, which consists in comparing the simulations of four institutional models: single term with candidates proposing, single term with parties proposing, two-term with candidates proposing and two-term with parties proposing. Valences of candidates and preferences for alternation of voters are two important components of the analysis. Simulations establish that two-term schemes are inefficient, while term limits is a second order component of the agenda setting bargaining, while the offering side is the main component.
Citation: |
Table 1. Preference order with negative incumbency advantage
Preference | $\succeq_{c_{2}}$3 | |||
$\frac{k_{A}}{k_{B}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$B$ $A$ |
$A/B$ $B/A$ |
$A$ $B$ |
Table 2. Preference order with negative incumbency advantage
Preference | $\succeq_{B}$4 | |||
$\frac{m_{1}}{m_{2}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$c_{2}$ $c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}/c_{2}$ $c_{2}/c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}$ $c_{2}$ |
Table 3. Preference order of B
Preference | $\succeq_{B}$5 | |||
$\frac{m_{1}}{m_{2}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$c_{2}$ $c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}/c_{2}$ $c_{2}/c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}$ $c_{2}$ |
Table 4. Preference order with positive incumbency advantage
Preference | $\succeq_{c_{2}}$7 | |||
$\frac{k_{A}}{k_{B}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$B$ $A$ |
$A/B$ $B/A$ |
$A$ $B$ |
Table 5. Preference order with positive incumbency advantage
Preference | $\succeq_{A}$8 | |||
$\frac{m_{1}}{m_{2}}$ | $<c$ | $=c$ | $>c$ | |
Most Least |
$c_{2}$ $c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}/c_{2}$ $c_{2}/c_{1}$ |
$c_{1}$ $c_{2}$ |
[1] |
J. H. Aldrich, Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America, University of Chicago Press, 1995.
![]() |
[2] |
K. Bawn, M. Cohen, D. Karol, S. Masket, H. Noel and J. Zaller, A theory of political parties: Groups, policy demands, and nominations in American politics, Perspectives on Politics, 10 (2012), 571-597.
![]() |
[3] |
J. M. Carey, R. G. Niemi, L. W. Powell and G. F. Moncrief, The effects of term limits on State Legislatures: A new survey of the 50 States, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 31 (2006), 105-134.
![]() |
[4] |
G. Cox and M. D. McCubbins, Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House, University of California Press, 1993.
![]() |
[5] |
B. A. Desmarais, R. J. La Raja and M. S. Kowal, The Fates of challengers in U.S. House Elections: The role of extended party networks in supporting candidates and shaping electoral outcomes, American Journal of Political Science, 59 (2015), 194-211.
doi: 10.1111/ajps.12106.![]() ![]() |
[6] |
A. Downs, An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy, Journal of Political Economy, 65 (1957), 135-150.
doi: 10.1086/257897.![]() ![]() |
[7] |
A. Glazer and M. P. Wattenberg, How will term limits affect legislative work?, in Legislative Term Limits: Public Choice Perspectives, B. Grofman (ed.), Studies in Public Choice, Springer, Dordrecht, 10 (1996), 37-46.
doi: 10.1007/978-94-009-1812-2_3.![]() ![]() |
[8] |
J. F. Flowers, A. A. Haynes and M. H. Crespin, The media, the campaign, and the message, American Journal of Political Science, 47 (2003), 259-273.
doi: 10.1111/1540-5907.00018.![]() ![]() |
[9] |
C. Green-Pedersen and P. B. Mortensen, Who sets the agenda and who responds to it in the Danish Parliament? A new model of issue competition and agenda-setting, European Journal of Political Research, 49 (2010), 257-281.
doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2009.01897.x.![]() ![]() |
[10] |
F. Herrera López, Voting with preference for alternation, Ph.D. Thesis, Chapter 2, El Colegio de México, (2019), 39-75.
![]() |
[11] |
R. G. Holcombe and J. D. Gwartney, Political parties and the legislative principal-agent relationship, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145 (1989), 669-675.
![]() |
[12] |
K. F. Kahn, The distorted mirror: Press coverage of women candidates for Statewide Office, The Journal of Politics, 56 (1994), 154-173.
doi: 10.2307/2132350.![]() ![]() |
[13] |
H. Klüver and I. Sagarzazu, Setting the agenda or responding to voters? Political parties, voters and issue attention, West European Politics, 39 (2016), 380-398.
doi: 10.1080/01402382.2015.1101295.![]() ![]() |
[14] |
M. McCombs, Setting the Ggenda: The Mass Media and Public opinion, Blackwell Publishers, 2004.
![]() |
[15] |
G. Serra, Polarization of what? a model of elections with endogenous valence, The Journal of Politics, 72 (2010), 426-437.
doi: 10.1017/S0022381609990880.![]() ![]() |
[16] |
G. Serra, Why primaries? The party's tradeoff between policy and valence, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 23 (2011), 21-51.
doi: 10.1177/0951629810382805.![]() ![]() |
[17] |
G. Serra, The electoral strategies of a populist candidate: Does charisma discourage experience and encourage extremism?, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 30 (2018), 45-73.
doi: 10.1177/0951629817737860.![]() ![]() |
[18] |
D. E. Stokes, Spatial models of party competition, The American Political Science Review, 57 (1963), 368-377.
![]() |
[19] |
R. M. Skinner, S. E. Masket and D. A. Dulio, 527 committees and the political party network, American Politics Research, 40 (2011), 60-84.
doi: 10.1177/1532673X11420420.![]() ![]() |
Single term game with offers by parties
Preferences of
Single term game with offers by candidates
Preferences of
Two term game with offers by parties
Single term game with offers by candidates
Preferences of
Stationary state with negative advantage
Stationary state with large positive advantage
Stationary state with mixed advantages
Efficiency with varying advantages
Share of power
Preferences of
Preferences of