doi: 10.3934/krm.2020051

Evolutionary game theory in mixed strategies: From microscopic interactions to kinetic equations

IMAS (UBA-CONICET) and Departamento de Matemática, Facultad de Ciencias Exactas y Naturales, Universidad de Buenos Aires, Ciudad Universitaria, 1428 Buenos Aires, Argentina

Received  March 2020 Revised  August 2020 Published  November 2020

Fund Project: This work was partially supported by Universidad de Buenos Aires under grants 20020170100445BA and 20020170200256BA, by Agencia Nacional de Promocion Cientifica y Tecnica PICT 201-0215 and PICT 2016 1022

In this work we propose a kinetic formulation for evolutionary game theory for zero sum games when the agents use mixed strategies. We start with a simple adaptive rule, where after an encounter each agent increases by a small amount $ h $ the probability of playing the successful pure strategy used in the match. We derive the Boltzmann equation which describes the macroscopic effects of this microscopical rule, and we obtain a first order, nonlocal, partial differential equation as the limit when $ h $ goes to zero.

We study the relationship between this equation and the well known replicator equations, showing the equivalence between the concepts of Nash equilibria, stationary solutions of the partial differential equation, and the equilibria of the replicator equations. Finally, we relate the long-time behavior of solutions to the partial differential equation and the stability of the replicator equations.

Citation: Juan Pablo Pinasco, Mauro Rodriguez Cartabia, Nicolas Saintier. Evolutionary game theory in mixed strategies: From microscopic interactions to kinetic equations. Kinetic & Related Models, doi: 10.3934/krm.2020051
References:
[1]

A. S. Ackleh and N. Saintier, Well-posedness of a system of transport and diffusion equations in space of measures, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 492 (2020), 28 pp. doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2020.124397.  Google Scholar

[2]

G. AlbiL. Pareschi and M. Zanella, Boltzmann games in heterogeneous consensus dynamics, Journal of Statistical Physics, 175 (2019), 97-125.  doi: 10.1007/s10955-019-02246-y.  Google Scholar

[3]

R. Alonso, I. M. Gamba and M.-B. Tran, The Cauchy problem and BEC stability for the quantum Boltzmann-condensation system for bosons at very low temperature, arXiv preprint arxiv: 1609.07467, (2016). Google Scholar

[4]

L. Ambrosio, M. Fornasier, M. Morandotti and G. Savare, Spatially inhomogeneous evolutionary games, arXiv preprint arxiv: 1805.04027, (2018). Google Scholar

[5]

L. ArlottiN. Bellomo and and E. De Angelis, Generalized kinetic (Boltzmann) models: Mathematical structures and applications, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 12 (2002), 567-591.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202502001799.  Google Scholar

[6]

N. Bellomo, Modeling Complex Living Systems: A Kinetic Theory and Stochastic Game Approach, Birkhäuser Boston, Inc., Boston, MA, 2008.  Google Scholar

[7]

G. A. Marsan, N. Bellomo and A. Tosin, Complex Systems and Society: Modeling and Simulation, Springer, 2013. doi: 10.1007/978-1-4614-7242-1.  Google Scholar

[8]

A. BoccabellaR. Natalini and L. Pareschi, On a continuous mixed strategies model for evolutionary game theory, Kinetic and Related Models, 4 (2011), 187-213.  doi: 10.3934/krm.2011.4.187.  Google Scholar

[9]

W. Braun and K. Hepp, The Vlasov dynamics and its fluctuations in the $1/n$ limit of interacting classical particles, Communications in Mathematical Physics, 56 (1977), 101-113.  doi: 10.1007/BF01611497.  Google Scholar

[10]

A. Bressan, Notes on the Boltzmann Equation, Lecture notes for a summer course, SISSA Trieste, (2005). Google Scholar

[11]

J. A. CanizoJ. A. Carrillo and J. Rosado, A well-posedness theory in measures for some kinetic models of collective motion, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 21 (2011), 515-539.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202511005131.  Google Scholar

[12]

C. Cercignani, R. Illner and M. Pulvirenti, The Mathematical Theory of Dilute Gases, vol. 106, Springer Science & Business Media, 2013. Google Scholar

[13]

J. Cleveland and A. S. Ackleh, Evolutionary game theory on measure spaces: Well-posedness, Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications, 14 (2013), 785-797.  doi: 10.1016/j.nonrwa.2012.08.002.  Google Scholar

[14]

R. Cressman, Stability of the replicator equation with continuous strategy space, Mathematical Social Sciences, 50 (2005), 127-147.  doi: 10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2005.03.001.  Google Scholar

[15]

——, The Stability Concept of Evolutionary Game Theory: A Dynamic Approach, vol. 94, Springer Science & Business Media, 2013. Google Scholar

[16]

P. Degond and B. Lucquin-Desreux, The Fokker-Planck asymptotics of the Boltzmann collision operator in the Coulomb case, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 2 (1992), 167-182.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202592000119.  Google Scholar

[17]

L. Desvillettes, On asymptotics of the Boltzmann equation when the collisions become grazing, Transport Theory and Statistical Physics, 21 (1992), 259-276.  doi: 10.1080/00411459208203923.  Google Scholar

[18]

L. Desvillettes and V. Ricci, A rigorous derivation of a linear kinetic equation of Fokker-Planck type in the limit of grazing collisions, Journal of Statistical Physics, 104 (2001), 1173-1189.  doi: 10.1023/A:1010461929872.  Google Scholar

[19]

R. L. Dobrushin, Vlasov equations, Functional Analysis and Its Applications, 13 (1979), 48-58.  doi: 10.1007/BF01077243.  Google Scholar

[20]

G. GabettaG. Toscani and B. Wennberg, Metrics for probability distributions and the trend to equilibrium for solutions of the Boltzmann equation, Journal of statistical physics, 81 (1995), 901-934.  doi: 10.1007/BF02179298.  Google Scholar

[21]

J. Geanakoplos, Nash and Walras equilibrium via Brouwer, Economic Theory, 21 (2003), 585-603.  doi: 10.1007/s001990000076.  Google Scholar

[22]

F. Golse, On the dynamics of large particle systems in the mean field limit, in Macroscopic and large scale phenomena: Coarse graining, mean field limits and ergodicity, Springer, 2016, 1-144. doi: 10.1007/978-3-319-26883-5_1.  Google Scholar

[23] J. Hofbauer and K. Sigmund, Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics, Cambridge University Press, 1998.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9781139173179.  Google Scholar
[24]

J. Hofbauer and K. Sigmund, Evolutionary game dynamics, Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, 40 (2003), 479-519.  doi: 10.1090/S0273-0979-03-00988-1.  Google Scholar

[25]

R. Laraki, J. Renault and S. Sorin, Mathematical Foundations of Game Theory, Springer, Cham, (2019). doi: 10.1007/978-3-030-26646-2.  Google Scholar

[26]

G. A. MarsanN. Bellomo and L. Gibelli, Stochastic evolutionary differential games toward a systems theory of behavioral social dynamics, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 26 (2016), 1051-1093.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202516500251.  Google Scholar

[27]

S. Mendoza-Palacios and O. Hernández-Lerma, Evolutionary dynamics on measurable strategy spaces: Asymmetric games, Journal of Differential Equations, 259 (2015), 5709-5733.  doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2015.07.005.  Google Scholar

[28]

J. Miekisz, Evolutionary game theory and population dynamics, in Multiscale Problems in the Life Sciences, Springer, 2008, 269-316. doi: 10.1007/978-3-540-78362-6_5.  Google Scholar

[29]

G. Naldi, L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Mathematical Modeling of Collective Behavior in Socio-Economic and Life Sciences, Springer Science & Business Media, 2010. doi: 10.1007/978-0-8176-4946-3.  Google Scholar

[30]

H. Neunzert and J. Wick, Die approximation der Lösung von integro-differentialgleichungen durch endliche punktmengen, in Numerische Behandlung nichtlinearer Integrodifferential-und Differentialgleichungen, Springer, 1974, 275-290.  Google Scholar

[31]

J. Oechssler and F. Riedel, Evolutionary dynamics on infinite strategy spaces, Economic Theory, 17 (2001), 141-162.  doi: 10.1007/PL00004092.  Google Scholar

[32]

S. Onn and I. Weissman, Generating uniform random vectors over a simplex with implications to the volume of a certain polytope and to multivariate extremes., Ann Oper Res, 189 (2011), 331-342.  doi: 10.1007/s10479-009-0567-7.  Google Scholar

[33]

L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Interacting Multiagent Systems: Kinetic Equations and Monte Carlo Methods, OUP Oxford, 2013. Google Scholar

[34]

L. PedrazaJ. P. Pinasco and N. Saintier, Measure-valued opinion dynamics, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 30 (2020), 225-260.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202520500062.  Google Scholar

[35]

M. Pérez-Llanos, J. P. Pinasco, and N. Saintier, Opinion fitness and convergence to consensus in homogeneous and heterogeneous populations, 2020. Google Scholar

[36]

M. Pérez-LlanosJ. P. PinascoN. Saintier and A. Silva, Opinion formation models with heterogeneous persuasion and zealotry, SIAM Journal on Mathematical Analysis, 50 (2018), 4812-4837.  doi: 10.1137/17M1152784.  Google Scholar

[37]

J. P. PinascoM. R. Cartabia and N. Saintier, A game theoretic model of wealth distribution, Dynamic Games and Applications, 8 (2018), 874-890.  doi: 10.1007/s13235-018-0240-3.  Google Scholar

[38]

F. Salvarani and D. Tonon, Kinetic Description of Strategic Binary Games, 2019. Google Scholar

[39] W. H. Sandholm, Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics, MIT press, 2010.   Google Scholar
[40]

P. Schuster and K. Sigmund, Replicator dynamics, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 100 (1983), 533-538.  doi: 10.1016/0022-5193(83)90445-9.  Google Scholar

[41]

F. Slanina and H. Lavicka, Analytical results for the Sznajd model of opinion formation, The European Physical Journal B, 35 (2003), 279-288.  doi: 10.1140/epjb/e2003-00278-0.  Google Scholar

[42] J. M. Smith, Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge university press, 1982.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511806292.  Google Scholar
[43]

P. D. Taylor and L. B. Jonker, Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics, Mathematical Biosciences, 40 (1978), 145-156.  doi: 10.1016/0025-5564(78)90077-9.  Google Scholar

[44]

G. Toscani, Kinetic models of opinion formation, Communications in Mathematical Sciences, 4 (2006), 481-496.  doi: 10.4310/CMS.2006.v4.n3.a1.  Google Scholar

[45]

A. Tosin, Kinetic equations and stochastic game theory for social systems, in Mathematical Models and Methods for Planet Earth, Springer, 2014, 37-57. doi: 10.1007/978-3-319-02657-2_4.  Google Scholar

[46]

C. Villani, Topics in Optimal Transportation, American Mathematical Soc., 2003. doi: 10.1090/gsm/058.  Google Scholar

[47]

A. Wornow, Generating random numebrs on a simplex, Computers and Geosciences, 19 (1993), 81-88.  doi: 10.1016/0098-3004(93)90045-7.  Google Scholar

show all references

References:
[1]

A. S. Ackleh and N. Saintier, Well-posedness of a system of transport and diffusion equations in space of measures, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 492 (2020), 28 pp. doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2020.124397.  Google Scholar

[2]

G. AlbiL. Pareschi and M. Zanella, Boltzmann games in heterogeneous consensus dynamics, Journal of Statistical Physics, 175 (2019), 97-125.  doi: 10.1007/s10955-019-02246-y.  Google Scholar

[3]

R. Alonso, I. M. Gamba and M.-B. Tran, The Cauchy problem and BEC stability for the quantum Boltzmann-condensation system for bosons at very low temperature, arXiv preprint arxiv: 1609.07467, (2016). Google Scholar

[4]

L. Ambrosio, M. Fornasier, M. Morandotti and G. Savare, Spatially inhomogeneous evolutionary games, arXiv preprint arxiv: 1805.04027, (2018). Google Scholar

[5]

L. ArlottiN. Bellomo and and E. De Angelis, Generalized kinetic (Boltzmann) models: Mathematical structures and applications, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 12 (2002), 567-591.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202502001799.  Google Scholar

[6]

N. Bellomo, Modeling Complex Living Systems: A Kinetic Theory and Stochastic Game Approach, Birkhäuser Boston, Inc., Boston, MA, 2008.  Google Scholar

[7]

G. A. Marsan, N. Bellomo and A. Tosin, Complex Systems and Society: Modeling and Simulation, Springer, 2013. doi: 10.1007/978-1-4614-7242-1.  Google Scholar

[8]

A. BoccabellaR. Natalini and L. Pareschi, On a continuous mixed strategies model for evolutionary game theory, Kinetic and Related Models, 4 (2011), 187-213.  doi: 10.3934/krm.2011.4.187.  Google Scholar

[9]

W. Braun and K. Hepp, The Vlasov dynamics and its fluctuations in the $1/n$ limit of interacting classical particles, Communications in Mathematical Physics, 56 (1977), 101-113.  doi: 10.1007/BF01611497.  Google Scholar

[10]

A. Bressan, Notes on the Boltzmann Equation, Lecture notes for a summer course, SISSA Trieste, (2005). Google Scholar

[11]

J. A. CanizoJ. A. Carrillo and J. Rosado, A well-posedness theory in measures for some kinetic models of collective motion, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 21 (2011), 515-539.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202511005131.  Google Scholar

[12]

C. Cercignani, R. Illner and M. Pulvirenti, The Mathematical Theory of Dilute Gases, vol. 106, Springer Science & Business Media, 2013. Google Scholar

[13]

J. Cleveland and A. S. Ackleh, Evolutionary game theory on measure spaces: Well-posedness, Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications, 14 (2013), 785-797.  doi: 10.1016/j.nonrwa.2012.08.002.  Google Scholar

[14]

R. Cressman, Stability of the replicator equation with continuous strategy space, Mathematical Social Sciences, 50 (2005), 127-147.  doi: 10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2005.03.001.  Google Scholar

[15]

——, The Stability Concept of Evolutionary Game Theory: A Dynamic Approach, vol. 94, Springer Science & Business Media, 2013. Google Scholar

[16]

P. Degond and B. Lucquin-Desreux, The Fokker-Planck asymptotics of the Boltzmann collision operator in the Coulomb case, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 2 (1992), 167-182.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202592000119.  Google Scholar

[17]

L. Desvillettes, On asymptotics of the Boltzmann equation when the collisions become grazing, Transport Theory and Statistical Physics, 21 (1992), 259-276.  doi: 10.1080/00411459208203923.  Google Scholar

[18]

L. Desvillettes and V. Ricci, A rigorous derivation of a linear kinetic equation of Fokker-Planck type in the limit of grazing collisions, Journal of Statistical Physics, 104 (2001), 1173-1189.  doi: 10.1023/A:1010461929872.  Google Scholar

[19]

R. L. Dobrushin, Vlasov equations, Functional Analysis and Its Applications, 13 (1979), 48-58.  doi: 10.1007/BF01077243.  Google Scholar

[20]

G. GabettaG. Toscani and B. Wennberg, Metrics for probability distributions and the trend to equilibrium for solutions of the Boltzmann equation, Journal of statistical physics, 81 (1995), 901-934.  doi: 10.1007/BF02179298.  Google Scholar

[21]

J. Geanakoplos, Nash and Walras equilibrium via Brouwer, Economic Theory, 21 (2003), 585-603.  doi: 10.1007/s001990000076.  Google Scholar

[22]

F. Golse, On the dynamics of large particle systems in the mean field limit, in Macroscopic and large scale phenomena: Coarse graining, mean field limits and ergodicity, Springer, 2016, 1-144. doi: 10.1007/978-3-319-26883-5_1.  Google Scholar

[23] J. Hofbauer and K. Sigmund, Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics, Cambridge University Press, 1998.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9781139173179.  Google Scholar
[24]

J. Hofbauer and K. Sigmund, Evolutionary game dynamics, Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, 40 (2003), 479-519.  doi: 10.1090/S0273-0979-03-00988-1.  Google Scholar

[25]

R. Laraki, J. Renault and S. Sorin, Mathematical Foundations of Game Theory, Springer, Cham, (2019). doi: 10.1007/978-3-030-26646-2.  Google Scholar

[26]

G. A. MarsanN. Bellomo and L. Gibelli, Stochastic evolutionary differential games toward a systems theory of behavioral social dynamics, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 26 (2016), 1051-1093.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202516500251.  Google Scholar

[27]

S. Mendoza-Palacios and O. Hernández-Lerma, Evolutionary dynamics on measurable strategy spaces: Asymmetric games, Journal of Differential Equations, 259 (2015), 5709-5733.  doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2015.07.005.  Google Scholar

[28]

J. Miekisz, Evolutionary game theory and population dynamics, in Multiscale Problems in the Life Sciences, Springer, 2008, 269-316. doi: 10.1007/978-3-540-78362-6_5.  Google Scholar

[29]

G. Naldi, L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Mathematical Modeling of Collective Behavior in Socio-Economic and Life Sciences, Springer Science & Business Media, 2010. doi: 10.1007/978-0-8176-4946-3.  Google Scholar

[30]

H. Neunzert and J. Wick, Die approximation der Lösung von integro-differentialgleichungen durch endliche punktmengen, in Numerische Behandlung nichtlinearer Integrodifferential-und Differentialgleichungen, Springer, 1974, 275-290.  Google Scholar

[31]

J. Oechssler and F. Riedel, Evolutionary dynamics on infinite strategy spaces, Economic Theory, 17 (2001), 141-162.  doi: 10.1007/PL00004092.  Google Scholar

[32]

S. Onn and I. Weissman, Generating uniform random vectors over a simplex with implications to the volume of a certain polytope and to multivariate extremes., Ann Oper Res, 189 (2011), 331-342.  doi: 10.1007/s10479-009-0567-7.  Google Scholar

[33]

L. Pareschi and G. Toscani, Interacting Multiagent Systems: Kinetic Equations and Monte Carlo Methods, OUP Oxford, 2013. Google Scholar

[34]

L. PedrazaJ. P. Pinasco and N. Saintier, Measure-valued opinion dynamics, Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 30 (2020), 225-260.  doi: 10.1142/S0218202520500062.  Google Scholar

[35]

M. Pérez-Llanos, J. P. Pinasco, and N. Saintier, Opinion fitness and convergence to consensus in homogeneous and heterogeneous populations, 2020. Google Scholar

[36]

M. Pérez-LlanosJ. P. PinascoN. Saintier and A. Silva, Opinion formation models with heterogeneous persuasion and zealotry, SIAM Journal on Mathematical Analysis, 50 (2018), 4812-4837.  doi: 10.1137/17M1152784.  Google Scholar

[37]

J. P. PinascoM. R. Cartabia and N. Saintier, A game theoretic model of wealth distribution, Dynamic Games and Applications, 8 (2018), 874-890.  doi: 10.1007/s13235-018-0240-3.  Google Scholar

[38]

F. Salvarani and D. Tonon, Kinetic Description of Strategic Binary Games, 2019. Google Scholar

[39] W. H. Sandholm, Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics, MIT press, 2010.   Google Scholar
[40]

P. Schuster and K. Sigmund, Replicator dynamics, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 100 (1983), 533-538.  doi: 10.1016/0022-5193(83)90445-9.  Google Scholar

[41]

F. Slanina and H. Lavicka, Analytical results for the Sznajd model of opinion formation, The European Physical Journal B, 35 (2003), 279-288.  doi: 10.1140/epjb/e2003-00278-0.  Google Scholar

[42] J. M. Smith, Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge university press, 1982.  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511806292.  Google Scholar
[43]

P. D. Taylor and L. B. Jonker, Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics, Mathematical Biosciences, 40 (1978), 145-156.  doi: 10.1016/0025-5564(78)90077-9.  Google Scholar

[44]

G. Toscani, Kinetic models of opinion formation, Communications in Mathematical Sciences, 4 (2006), 481-496.  doi: 10.4310/CMS.2006.v4.n3.a1.  Google Scholar

[45]

A. Tosin, Kinetic equations and stochastic game theory for social systems, in Mathematical Models and Methods for Planet Earth, Springer, 2014, 37-57. doi: 10.1007/978-3-319-02657-2_4.  Google Scholar

[46]

C. Villani, Topics in Optimal Transportation, American Mathematical Soc., 2003. doi: 10.1090/gsm/058.  Google Scholar

[47]

A. Wornow, Generating random numebrs on a simplex, Computers and Geosciences, 19 (1993), 81-88.  doi: 10.1016/0098-3004(93)90045-7.  Google Scholar

Figure 1.  Time evolution of the distribution of $ p^1_1, \ldots, p^N_1 $ obtained solving the transport equation (5.12) (left) and from an agent-based simulation (right).
Figure 2.  Time evolution of the distribution of $ p^1_1, \ldots, p^N_1 $, $ N=1000 $, in the agent-based simulation starting from a uniform distribution in $ [0, 0.3] $ with $ \delta=0.01 $ and different values of noise level $ r $.
Figure 3.  Averaged proportion of agents in the agent-based simulation with $ p\in [0, 0.01] $ at time $ \tau=800 $ in function of the noise level $ r $ (the average is computed over 10 simulations).
Figure 4.  Plot of $ \log(\max\, p_1-\min\, p_1) $ in the agent-based simulation with $ N=1000 $, $ \delta=c=0.01 $, $ r=0 $ and two different functions $ h $.
[1]

Illés Horváth, Kristóf Attila Horváth, Péter Kovács, Miklós Telek. Mean-field analysis of a scaling MAC radio protocol. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (1) : 279-297. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019111

[2]

Claudianor O. Alves, Rodrigo C. M. Nemer, Sergio H. Monari Soares. The use of the Morse theory to estimate the number of nontrivial solutions of a nonlinear Schrödinger equation with a magnetic field. Communications on Pure & Applied Analysis, 2021, 20 (1) : 449-465. doi: 10.3934/cpaa.2020276

[3]

Jie Li, Xiangdong Ye, Tao Yu. Mean equicontinuity, complexity and applications. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - A, 2021, 41 (1) : 359-393. doi: 10.3934/dcds.2020167

[4]

Felix Finster, Jürg Fröhlich, Marco Oppio, Claudio F. Paganini. Causal fermion systems and the ETH approach to quantum theory. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020451

[5]

Yueyang Zheng, Jingtao Shi. A stackelberg game of backward stochastic differential equations with partial information. Mathematical Control & Related Fields, 2020  doi: 10.3934/mcrf.2020047

[6]

Anna Abbatiello, Eduard Feireisl, Antoní Novotný. Generalized solutions to models of compressible viscous fluids. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - A, 2021, 41 (1) : 1-28. doi: 10.3934/dcds.2020345

[7]

Xin Guo, Lexin Li, Qiang Wu. Modeling interactive components by coordinate kernel polynomial models. Mathematical Foundations of Computing, 2020, 3 (4) : 263-277. doi: 10.3934/mfc.2020010

[8]

Ebraheem O. Alzahrani, Muhammad Altaf Khan. Androgen driven evolutionary population dynamics in prostate cancer growth. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020426

[9]

Shipra Singh, Aviv Gibali, Xiaolong Qin. Cooperation in traffic network problems via evolutionary split variational inequalities. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2020  doi: 10.3934/jimo.2020170

[10]

Martin Kalousek, Joshua Kortum, Anja Schlömerkemper. Mathematical analysis of weak and strong solutions to an evolutionary model for magnetoviscoelasticity. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2021, 14 (1) : 17-39. doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020331

[11]

Jian Zhang, Tony T. Lee, Tong Ye, Liang Huang. An approximate mean queue length formula for queueing systems with varying service rate. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2021, 17 (1) : 185-204. doi: 10.3934/jimo.2019106

[12]

Pierre-Etienne Druet. A theory of generalised solutions for ideal gas mixtures with Maxwell-Stefan diffusion. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020458

[13]

Parikshit Upadhyaya, Elias Jarlebring, Emanuel H. Rubensson. A density matrix approach to the convergence of the self-consistent field iteration. Numerical Algebra, Control & Optimization, 2021, 11 (1) : 99-115. doi: 10.3934/naco.2020018

[14]

Sergey Rashkovskiy. Hamilton-Jacobi theory for Hamiltonian and non-Hamiltonian systems. Journal of Geometric Mechanics, 2020, 12 (4) : 563-583. doi: 10.3934/jgm.2020024

[15]

Wei Feng, Michael Freeze, Xin Lu. On competition models under allee effect: Asymptotic behavior and traveling waves. Communications on Pure & Applied Analysis, 2020, 19 (12) : 5609-5626. doi: 10.3934/cpaa.2020256

[16]

Youming Guo, Tingting Li. Optimal control strategies for an online game addiction model with low and high risk exposure. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - B, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdsb.2020347

[17]

Dan Zhu, Rosemary A. Renaut, Hongwei Li, Tianyou Liu. Fast non-convex low-rank matrix decomposition for separation of potential field data using minimal memory. Inverse Problems & Imaging, , () : -. doi: 10.3934/ipi.2020076

[18]

Yuanfen Xiao. Mean Li-Yorke chaotic set along polynomial sequence with full Hausdorff dimension for $ \beta $-transformation. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - A, 2021, 41 (2) : 525-536. doi: 10.3934/dcds.2020267

[19]

Yongge Tian, Pengyang Xie. Simultaneous optimal predictions under two seemingly unrelated linear random-effects models. Journal of Industrial & Management Optimization, 2020  doi: 10.3934/jimo.2020168

[20]

Annegret Glitzky, Matthias Liero, Grigor Nika. Dimension reduction of thermistor models for large-area organic light-emitting diodes. Discrete & Continuous Dynamical Systems - S, 2020  doi: 10.3934/dcdss.2020460

2019 Impact Factor: 1.311

Metrics

  • PDF downloads (14)
  • HTML views (29)
  • Cited by (0)

[Back to Top]