\`x^2+y_1+z_12^34\`
Advanced Search
Article Contents
Article Contents

Rank-dependent predictable forward performance processes

  • Corresponding author: Bahman Angoshtari

    Corresponding author: Bahman Angoshtari 
Abstract / Introduction Full Text(HTML) Figure(4) Related Papers Cited by
  • Predictable forward performance processes (PFPPs) are stochastic optimal control frameworks for an agent who controls a randomly evolving system but can only prescribe the system dynamics for a short period ahead. This is a common scenario in which a controlling agent frequently re-calibrates her model. We introduce a new class of PFPPs based on rank-dependent utility, generalizing existing models that are based on expected utility theory (EUT). We establish existence of rank-dependent PFPPs under a conditionally complete market and exogenous probability distortion functions which are updated periodically. We show that their construction reduces to solving an integral equation that generalizes the integral equation obtained under EUT in previous studies. We then propose a new approach for solving the integral equation via theory of Volterra equations. We illustrate our result in the special case of conditionally complete Black-Scholes model.

    Mathematics Subject Classification: 91G10, 91G80, 60H30.

    Citation:

    \begin{equation} \\ \end{equation}
  • 加载中
  • Figure 1.  On left: Plots of six probability weighting functions: $ W(p):= p^{0.69} \Big(p^{0.69}+(1-p)^{0.69}\Big)^{-\frac{1}{0.69}} $ from [27] (the solid black curve); $ W(p)=0.65 p^{0.6} \Big(0.65 p^{0.6}+(1-p)^{0.6}\Big)^{-1} $ from [26] (the dashed blue curve); $ W(p)=\exp\left(-0.65\big(-\ln(p)\big)^{0.74}\right) $ from [21] (red dashed–dotted curve); $ W(p)=p $ (the cyan dotted line); a concave probability weighting function $ w(p)=p^{0.2} $ (the green dashdotdotted curve); and an extreme S-shaped probability weighting function $ W(p):= p^{0.3} \Big(p^{0.3}+(1-p)^{0.3}\Big)^{-\frac{1}{0.3}} $ (the purple long dashed curve). Parameter values for the first three are taken from various empirical studies, see page 9 of [9]. The last two probability weighting function are unrealistic as they highly overweight probabilities of extreme events. They are included to highlight the effect of probability weighting function on the RDPFPPs (See Figure 4). On right: The corresponding plots of the functions $ \Phi(\cdot) $ given by (7.3) for each probability weighting function and assuming the market Sharpe-ratio $ \lambda=0.4 $

    Figure 2.  Each row corresponds to one probability weighting function in Figure 1. Left plots illustrate the $ \overline{\Phi}(\cdot) $, the concave envelope of each $ \Phi(\cdot) $ in Figure 1. Middle plots show the corresponding kernel $ k(1,\cdot) $ given by (7.4) and the corresponding resolvent kernel $ {k^*}(1,\cdot) := \sum_{i=1}^\infty k_i(1,\cdot) $, with the iterated kernels $ k_i(1,\cdot) $ given by (7.5). Right plots show the size of $ \sup_{0<\xi\le1} |k_i(1,\xi)| $ for different $ i $. Note that the vertical axis has a logarithmic scale. Since $ k_i(1,\cdot) $ vanish for sufficiently large $ i $, we can approximate $ {k^*}(1,\cdot) $ by summing a finite number of iterated kernels.

    Figure 3.  Top left: Plots of three initial inverse marginal functions, namely, $ I_0(\cdot) $ given by (7.7) (red dashed-dotted curve), $ I_0(\cdot) $ given by (7.8) (the solid black curve), and $ I_0(\cdot) $ in (7.9) (the blue dashed curve). The first two belong to the special class of CMIM function with representation (6.4), while the third one is a CMIM function that does not belong to this class. Top right: The solutions $ I(y) $ of (7.2) for each of the three initial inverse marginals, the [27] probability weighting function (see Figure 1), and a market Sharpe-ratio $ \lambda=0.4 $. Each curve is computed numerically via (7.6), with $ q_0 $, $ \Phi'(\cdot) $, and $ {k^*}(1,\cdot) $ in the top row of Figure 2. For first two inverse marginals (namely, the red dashed-dotted curve and black solid curve), the solution $ I(y) $ can be found directly via the closed-form formula (6.6). These values are shown as data points (namely, the red circles and the black crosses), and match the numerical values calculated via the resolvent formula (7.6). There is no closed-form solution for the third inverse marginal (i.e. the blue dashed curve), as it does not belong the the special class of CMIM functions of the form (6.4). Note also that the third curve is less sensitive to the change of the probability weighting function. Bottom: The solutions $ I(y) $ of (7.2) for probability weighting functions in [26] and [21].

    Figure 4.  Sensitivity of the solutions $ I(y) $ of (7.2) with respect to the probability weighting function $ W(\cdot) $ and the market Sharpe-ratio $ \lambda $. In both plots, the initial inverse marginal function $ I_0(\cdot) $ is given by (7.8) and is illustrated by the thin dotted green curve. On left: The solution $ I(y) $ of (7.2) corresponding to six different probability weighting functions from Figure 1 and assuming the market Sharpe-ratio $ \lambda=0.4 $. Note that $ I(y) $ corresponding to the identity weighting function (i.e. the expected utility criterion) is closest to the initial inverse marginal function $ I_0(\cdot) $, while the one corresponding to concave probability weighting function $ w(p)=p^{0.2} $ is the farthest away. The realistic probability weighting functions (i.e. those taken from [27, 26, 21]) yield solutions $ I(y) $ in between. Note also that that the solution corresponding to probability weighting functions from [27, 26] almost coincide. On right: Similar plot corresponding to a higher market Sharpe-ratio $ \lambda=1.5 $. Note also that the solutions I(y) corresponding to the more realistic probability weighting functions (those taken from [27, 26, 21] plus the identity) are more sensitive to the change of $\lambda $.

  • [1]

    Angoshtari, B., Predictable forward performance processes in complete markets, Probability, Uncertainty and Quantitative Risk, 2023, 8(2): 141−176.

    doi: 10.3934/puqr.2023007.

    [2]

    Angoshtari, B., Zariphopoulou, T. and Zhou, X. Y., Predictable forward performance processes: The binomial case, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 2020, 58(1): 327−347.

    doi: 10.1137/18M1188653.

    [3]

    Bernstein, S., Sur les fonctions absolument monotones, Acta Mathematica, 1929, 52(1): 1−66.

    doi: 10.1007/BF02592679.

    [4]

    Carlier, G. and Dana, R.-A., Optimal demand for contingent claims when agents have law invariant utilities, Mathematical Finance, 2011, 21(2): 169−201.

    doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2010.00431.x.

    [5] Corduneanu, C., Integral Equations and Applications, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
    [6]

    He, X. D., Kouwenberg, R. and Zhou, X. Y., Rank-dependent utility and risk taking in complete markets, SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2017, 8(1): 214−239.

    doi: 10.1137/16M1072516.

    [7]

    He, X. D., Strub, M. S. and Zariphopoulou, T., Forward rank-dependent performance criteria: Time-consistent investment under probability distortion, Mathematical Finance, 2021, 31(2): 683−721.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12298.

    [8]

    He, X. D. and Zhou, X. Y., Portfolio choice via quantiles, Mathematical Finance, 2011, 21(2): 203−231.

    doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2010.00432.x.

    [9]

    He, X. D. and Zhou, X. Y., Hope, fear, and aspirations, Mathematical Finance, 2016, 26(1): 3−50.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12044.

    [10]

    Hu, Y., Jin, H. and Zhou, X. Y., Consistent investment of sophisticated rank-dependent utility agents in continuous time, Mathematical Finance, 2021, 31(3): 1056−1095.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12315.

    [11]

    Jin, H., Xia, J. and Zhou, X. Y., Arrow-debreu equilibria for rank-dependent utilities with heterogeneous probability weighting, Mathematical Finance, 2019, 29(3): 898−927.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12200.

    [12]

    Jin, H. and Zhou, X. Y., Behavioral portfolio selection in continuous time, Mathematical Finance, 2008, 18(3): 385−426.

    doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2008.00339.x.

    [13]

    Källblad, S., Black’s inverse investment problem and forward criteria with consumption, SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2020, 11(2): 494−525.

    doi: 10.1137/17M1143812.

    [14] Liang, G., Strub, M. S. and Wang, Y., Predictable relative forward performance processes: Multiagent and mean field games for portfolio management, arXiv: 2311.04841, 2023.
    [15]

    Liang, G., Strub, M. S. and Wang, Y., Predictable forward performance processes: Infrequent evaluation and applications to human-machine interactions, Mathematical Finance, 2023, 33(4): 1248−1286.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12408.

    [16] Liang, G., Sun, Y. and Zariphopoulou, T., Representation of forward performance criteria with random endowment via fbsde and application to forward optimized certainty equivalent, arXiv: 2401.00103, 2023.
    [17]

    Musiela, M. and Zariphopoulou, T., Portfolio choice under dynamic investment performance criteria, Quantitative Finance, 2009, 9(2): 161−170.

    doi: 10.1080/14697680802624997.

    [18]

    Musiela, M. and Zariphopoulou, T., Portfolio choice under space time monotone performance criteria, SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2010, 1(1): 326−365.

    doi: 10.1137/080745250.

    [19]

    Musiela, M. and Zariphopoulou, T., Stochastic partial differential equations and portfolio choice, In: Chiarella, C. and Novikov, A.(eds.), Contemporary Quantitative Finance, Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, 2010: 195–216.

    [20]

    Musiela, M. and Zariphopoulou, T., Initial investment choice and optimal future allocations under time-monotone performance criteria, International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 2011, 14(1): 61−81.

    doi: 10.1142/S0219024911006267.

    [21] Prelec, D., The probability weighting function, Econometrica, 1998, 66(3): 497–527.
    [22]

    Quiggin, J., A theory of anticipated utility, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1982, 3(4): 323−343.

    [23]

    Riedel, F., Dynamic coherent risk measures, Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 2004, 112(2): 185−200.

    doi: 10.1016/j.spa.2004.03.004.

    [24] Schilling, R. L., Song, R. and Vondracek, Z., Bernstein Functions: Theory and Applications, De Gruyter, Berlin, Boston, 2012.
    [25]

    Strub, M. S. and Zhou, X. Y., Evolution of the arrow-pratt measure of risk-tolerance for predictable forward utility processes, Finance and Stochastics, 2021, 25(2): 331−358.

    doi: 10.1007/s00780-020-00444-1.

    [26]

    Tversky, A. and Fox, C. R., Weighing risk and uncertainty, Psychological Review, 1995, 102(2): 269.

    doi: 10.1037/0033-295X.102.2.269.

    [27]

    Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D., Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1992, 5: 297−323.

    doi: 10.1007/BF00122574.

    [28]

    Waldon, H., Forward robust portfolio selection: The binomial case, Probability, Uncertainty and Quantitative Risk, 2024, 9(1): 107−122.

    doi: 10.3934/puqr.2024006.

    [29]

    Xia, J. and Zhou, X. Y., Arrow-debreu equilibria for rank-dependent utilities, Mathematical Finance, 2016, 26(3): 558−588.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12070.

    [30]

    Xu, Z. Q., A new characterization of comonotonicity and its application in behavioral finance, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 2014, 418(2): 612−625.

    doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2014.03.053.

    [31]

    Xu, Z. Q., A note on the quantile formulation, Mathematical Finance, 2016, 26(3): 589−601.

    doi: 10.1111/mafi.12072.

  • 加载中

Figures(4)

SHARE

Article Metrics

HTML views(958) PDF downloads(165) Cited by(0)

Access History

Other Articles By Authors

Catalog

    /

    DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
    Return
    Return